AP Statistics / Mr. Hansen |
Name: _________KEY___________ |
1.
|
B, since normalcdf(−2.5,−1.5)=.0606
|
||
|
|
|
|
2.
|
A
|
||
|
|
||
3.
|
D
|
||
|
|
||
4.
|
D, since normalcdf(−99999,620,510,98)=.869
|
||
|
|
|
|
5.
|
B, since
|
||
|
|
||
|
|
||
6.
|
A
|
||
|
|
|
|
7.
|
negatively
|
||
8.
|
a number that describes a population
|
||
9.
|
|
||
|
|
||
|
yes
|
||
10.
|
r2
|
||
|
explanatory
|
||
11.
|
strong negative linear [all three words are required]
|
||
12.
|
An r value close to 0 could result from a
random cloud of data points. However, it could also occur (a) as the result
of two or more clusters of strongly
patterned points that cause a low r
value when combined on the same scatterplot, or (b)
as the result of a strong nonlinear
pattern (e.g., quadratic or sinusoidal) that would almost completely cancel
out any linear correlation.
|
||
13.
|
(a) r2
= .776 = 77.6% for both parts, since r does not change if the roles of x and y are switched
|
||
|
(b) r = −.881
|
||
|
(c) r = .986
|
||
|
(d) Using
2-digit years, with x = year, y = Verhoovian
GP:
|
||
|
|
||
|
Using
4-digit years, with x = year, y = Verhoovian
GP:
|
||
|
|
||
|
[Either
method is acceptable, but you should clearly show which approach you
followed.]
|
||
|
|
||
|
(e) Using
x = tax rate as a decimal (e.g.,
.095 = 9.5%) and y = Verhoovian GP:
|
||
|
|
||
|
Using
x = tax rate as a percentage
omitting the % symbol, y = Verhoovian GP:
|
||
|
|
||
|
[Again,
either method is acceptable, but you should clearly show which approach you
followed.]
|
||
|
|
||
|
(f) Both
involve extrapolation. In (d), we are extrapolating for a year into the
future, and in (e), we are extrapolating for a tax
rate for which we have no data.
|
||
|
|
||
|
(g) Several
possible responses are given below. There is no single “right or wrong” answer
to this question.
1. Correlation,
even strong correlation, does not imply causation. Since the Verhoovian economy grew in real terms during all but two
of the periods shown (1981-82 had a 3.5% contraction of the economy, 1990-91
had a 2.1% contraction, but all other years were positive), one could
reasonably dispute whether tax rates have an effect at all. The mere passage
of time seems to predict growth. In fact, time is a better predictor of
economic performance than tax rate, since the r2 value for a time-GP model is (.986)2 =
.97, which is greater than the .776 found for the tax rate-GP model in part
(a). [Although time is a better predictor, no cause-and-effect relationship
can be inferred for time, either.]
2. Tax
rates may be an effect rather than a cause. In other words, when the economy
starts to falter, as it did in 1981-82 and again in 1990-91, the Verhoovian government may have to raise tax rates in
order to avoid large revenue shortfalls and deficits. Then, when the economy
improves, tax rates can be lowered because revenues are projected to be
plentiful once again.
3. Both
tax rates and GP are surely influenced by myriad lurking variables: laws,
regulations, weather-related disasters, seasonal variations, fashion trends,
influence peddling, conflicts of interest, etc. Finding any sort of
repeatable pattern amidst all the noise, in the absence of a controlled
experiment, is virtually impossible.
4. By
cleverly choosing the case one wishes to make, one can torture this small
table to say almost anything. For example, the average economic growth in
years when the tax rate remained unchanged (2.9%) was the same as the average
for years in which the tax rate was lowered from the previous year. Does that
mean that there is no economic advantage to lowering tax rates and that the
government should simply collect the additional revenue? Unfortunately, the
question is not well posed; statistics cannot answer the question. If
citizens are too poorly informed to consider the issue of lurking variables, then
almost any data will suffice to make an argument, and demagogues will rule.
The general reasoning fallacy is called post
hoc ergo propter hoc (Latin for “after this, therefore because of this”).
5. Here
is a really interesting lesson, one that you can hopefully avoid learning the
hard way if you adhere to an “honesty is the best policy” way of life. You
see, sometimes it happens that choosing an invalid model for self-serving
reasons can be “self-correcting” in the sense that the model no longer makes
the argument you wish it did. For example, despite the strong correlation (r = −.881) of the model that
uses tax rate to predict GP, that model predicts GP in 1997 to be only 2100
units, a mere 0.4% growth from 1996. The model that uses calendar year to
predict GP predicts GP in 1997 to be 2157 units, which is a much more robust
(and politically popular) 3.1% growth rate over 1996. Thus imagine how the
political debate might have proceeded in late 1996: Political Party A,
arguing for lower tax rates, trumpets their model’s strong correlation and
predicts 0.4% growth for 1997. Meanwhile, Political Party B says that Party A
is full of hot air, and growth for 1997 should be 3.1%, based on a model that
has stronger correlation, if tax
rates are kept unchanged. If the political spin machine latches onto the
(phony) distinction between 0.4% and 3.1%, it is clear who will win the
debate. Imagine the ads: “The ______ Party wants you to live with only 0.4%
growth next year. Maybe that’s good enough for them. But for working people, people like my family, that’s just not going to cut it. (Cut to voiceover
announcer, the one with the “movie” voice.) Tell Your Legislator that You Won’t
Settle for Four-Tenths of a Percent Either! Paid for by
Citizens for Responsible Usage of Data.” Of course, lost in the
shuffle is the fact that both A and B are using dubious models to perform
extrapolation, and thus . . . they are both wrong.
|
||